版權(quán)說(shuō)明:本文檔由用戶提供并上傳,收益歸屬內(nèi)容提供方,若內(nèi)容存在侵權(quán),請(qǐng)進(jìn)行舉報(bào)或認(rèn)領(lǐng)
文檔簡(jiǎn)介
1、THE LAW AND ECONOMICS OF MARRIAGE CONTRACTSIan SmithUniversity of St AndrewsAbstract. Growth in property ownership has raised the stakes in the distribution of financial assets on divorce. Given high risks of marital fai
2、lure, this has stimulated the demand for private ordering through enforceable marriage con- tracts. This paper surveys the existing law and economics literature and legal practice to consider the state of knowledge on th
3、e economic theory, scope and limits of written nuptial agreements.Keywords. Marriage Contracts; Prenuptial Agreements; Marital Property1. IntroductionWhile there is much scholarly investigation of the financial consequen
4、ces of marital breakdown,1 discussion of the private regulation of such outcomes using marriage contracts is less systematic. The topic of marital contracting to alter the divorce entitlements of the parties receives, fo
5、r example, only brief comments in the standard surveys of the economics of the family offered by Becker (1991), Bergstrom (1996; 1997), Cabrillo (1999), Cigno (1991), Ermisch (1993), Grossbard-Shechtman (1993), Pollak (1
6、985) and Weiss (1997). Empirically, the most frequent type of marital contract in common law jurisdictions is the ex post separation agreement drafted following marriage breakdown. Such post-marital separation agreements
7、 are typically preferred to a judicially determined divorce settlement both by divorcing couples (Farmer and Tiefenthaler, 2001) and by courts which rarely set aside privately negotiated solutions. Less numerous are ex a
8、nte separation agreements, comprising both prenuptial contracts written prior to marriage and those negotiated during a continuing marriage. Ex post separation agreements, signed at divorce, are relatively uncontroversia
9、l and have less analytically interesting characteristics than marital contracts nego- tiated either as a condition of the wedding or during an on-going marriage. The difference in theoretical significance arises because,
10、 in the case of ex post separa- tion agreements, execution and enforcement are almost contemporaneous whereas marital contracts require contingent contracting over a possibly distant and uncertain future event. The conse
11、quence is that marriage contracts involve issues of renegotiation and signalling, as well as the bargaining problems that also0950-0804/03/02 0201–25 JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC SURVEYS Vol. 17, No. 2 # Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
12、 2003, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main St., Malden, MA 02148, USA.equitable for a high proportion of cases. A legal regime characterized by judicial discretion, while accommodating marital heterogen
13、eity to some extent, introduces uncertainty over adjudication and may promote litigation. One response to the greater variety of marital circumstances, to more wide- spread awareness of the bitterness of adversarial divo
14、rce conflicts, and to higher financial stakes on divorce is the growth in demand for private ordering through marital contracts specifying post-dissolution entitlements. For (prospective) spouses, the private negotiation
15、 and individualized tailoring of divorce conse- quences according to circumstances and preferences may generate efficiency gains. For example, to the extent that relatively easy access to clean break, no-fault divorce ha
16、s attenuated incentives to invest in marriage, couples can protect marriage-specific capital by customizing support obligations (Dnes, 2000). In addition, couples may value the freedom privately to order their financial
17、affairs rather than having judicial solutions coercively imposed by the state, permitting amicable determination of property rights prior to or during marriage rather than litigiously in divorce proceedings (Grossbard-Sh
18、echtman and Lemennicier, 1999). Indeed, there is some evidence that negotiating a divorce settlement without legal intervention promotes compliance (Peters et al, 1993). On the supply side, Allen (1990) has argued that t
19、he state permits private marital contracting instead of imposing its uniform marriage contract when the benefits from flexibility exceed the judicial costs of using third party sanctions to ensure economic justice. Conte
20、mporary moves towards the contractualization of marriage, in which parties define their own relationship terms, is the corollary of its increasing conceptualization in terms of rights to property. Bell (1997) argues from
21、 an anthropological perspective that marriage traditionally conferred rights on a husband of sexual access to his wife. However, innovations in female contra- ceptive technology and the legalization of abortion have give
22、n greater sexual and reproductive autonomy to women. Marriage is no longer defined so much in terms of sexual rights but rather in terms of economic rights and consequences. It is distinguished from non-marital cohabitat
23、ion by its implications for property division, pension, housing, fiscal and inheritance benefits, as well as by greater entry and exit costs. This is true even in countries such as Sweden which seek neutral treatment of
24、different family forms. Swedish law typically treats nearly all spousal property as marital, to be pooled and divided equally on divorce, whereas that of cohabitants is treated as separate property (Bradley, 1996). Insof
25、ar as the institution of marriage is conceived primarily in terms of financial effects, this will naturally lend itself to private contracting. Moreover, many legal commentators have noted a retreat from the regulation o
26、f marriage in family law, creating a climate favourable to marital contracting. In particular, the focus is shifting from the legal obligations of partners to those of parents (Carbone, 2000). The move from partners to p
27、arents is evident in the advent of the clean break philosophy that severs spousal financial responsibilities in the divorce settlement but strictly enforces continuing child support payments. The trend towards the privat
溫馨提示
- 1. 本站所有資源如無(wú)特殊說(shuō)明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請(qǐng)下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
- 2. 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請(qǐng)聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權(quán)益歸上傳用戶所有。
- 3. 本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁(yè)內(nèi)容里面會(huì)有圖紙預(yù)覽,若沒有圖紙預(yù)覽就沒有圖紙。
- 4. 未經(jīng)權(quán)益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
- 5. 眾賞文庫(kù)僅提供信息存儲(chǔ)空間,僅對(duì)用戶上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護(hù)處理,對(duì)用戶上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對(duì)任何下載內(nèi)容負(fù)責(zé)。
- 6. 下載文件中如有侵權(quán)或不適當(dāng)內(nèi)容,請(qǐng)與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
- 7. 本站不保證下載資源的準(zhǔn)確性、安全性和完整性, 同時(shí)也不承擔(dān)用戶因使用這些下載資源對(duì)自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。
最新文檔
- [雙語(yǔ)翻譯]婚姻法外文翻譯--婚姻契約的法律與經(jīng)濟(jì)學(xué)
- [雙語(yǔ)翻譯]婚姻法外文翻譯--婚姻契約的法律與經(jīng)濟(jì)學(xué)中英全
- 2003年婚姻法外文翻譯--婚姻契約的法律與經(jīng)濟(jì)學(xué)(英文).PDF
- 2003年婚姻法外文翻譯--婚姻契約的法律與經(jīng)濟(jì)學(xué)
- 2003年婚姻法外文翻譯--婚姻契約的法律與經(jīng)濟(jì)學(xué).DOCX
- [雙語(yǔ)翻譯]--外文翻譯--行為經(jīng)濟(jì)學(xué)和宏觀經(jīng)濟(jì)模型(英文)
- 無(wú)效婚姻與可撤銷婚姻法律問(wèn)題研究.pdf
- 婚姻法
- 漢代婚姻法律文化研究.pdf
- 欺詐婚姻法律規(guī)制研究.pdf
- [雙語(yǔ)翻譯]--外文翻譯--行為經(jīng)濟(jì)學(xué)和宏觀經(jīng)濟(jì)模型
- [雙語(yǔ)翻譯]清算方法外文翻譯--企業(yè)估價(jià)清算方法的基礎(chǔ)(英文)
- 近代婚姻習(xí)俗與婚姻法規(guī)比較研究.pdf
- 淺析侗族婚姻習(xí)俗與現(xiàn)行婚姻法的沖突
- [雙語(yǔ)翻譯]物業(yè)管理外文翻譯--物業(yè)管理服務(wù)外包的經(jīng)濟(jì)學(xué)視角(英文)
- 唐代婚姻法律制度探析.pdf
- [雙語(yǔ)翻譯]--外文翻譯--行為經(jīng)濟(jì)學(xué)和宏觀經(jīng)濟(jì)模型(譯文)
- 芻議涉外婚姻法律問(wèn)題
- 《婚姻法解釋(三)》的法律價(jià)值分析
- 瑕疵婚姻法律制度研究.pdf
評(píng)論
0/150
提交評(píng)論