

版權(quán)說(shuō)明:本文檔由用戶提供并上傳,收益歸屬內(nèi)容提供方,若內(nèi)容存在侵權(quán),請(qǐng)進(jìn)行舉報(bào)或認(rèn)領(lǐng)
文檔簡(jiǎn)介
1、<p> 本科畢業(yè)論文外文翻譯</p><p> 外文題目:Consumption theories and consumers' assessments of subjective well-being.</p><p> 出 處:Journal of Consumer Affairs; Winter92, Vol. 26 Issue 2, p243, 19
2、p, 3 Charts </p><p> 作 者: MacDonald, Maurice Douthitt, Robin A.</p><p><b> 原 文:</b></p><p><b> ABSTRACT
3、</b></p><p> Presents a paper which examines the relationship between psychological well-being and objective, economic well-being as measured using three different economic theories of consumption beh
4、avior. Life cycle income hypothesis; Relative income hypothesis; Resource deficit hypothesis; Methods and discussion.</p><p> I. Introduction</p><p> The purpose of this research is to examine
5、 the relationship between psychological well-being and objective, economic well-being as measured using three different economic theories of consumption behavior. The theories examined are the life cycle income hypothesi
6、s, the relative income hypothesis, and a resource deficit hypothesis. The results from analyses of the Wisconsin Basic Needs Study data demonstrate the importance of careful economic variable construction and support the
7、 economic presumpt</p><p> This paper examines the relationships between subjective assessments of well-being and objective economic variables to test and compare three different economic theories of consum
8、ption behavior: Modigliani's life cycle income hypothesis (1986); Duesenberry's relative income hypothesis (1949); and a resource deficit hypothesis attributed to Kyrk (1953). Multivariate analyses were designed
9、to isolate and compare the independent effects on subjective well-being of objective economic measures repres</p><p> The following quotes provide an introduction to the main ideas for three different model
10、s of the relationship of changes in consumer resources to perceptions of well-being. </p><p> The hypothesis of utility maximization (and perfect markets) has, all by itself, one very powerful implication-t
11、he resources that a representative consumer allocates at any age ... will depend only on his life resources ... and not at all on income accruing currently (Modigliani 1986, 299). </p><p> From the viewpoin
12、t of preference theory or marginal utility theory, human desires are desires for specific goods; but nothing is said about how these desires arise or how they are changed. That, however, is the essence of the consumption
13、 problem when preferences are interdependent (Duesenberry 1949, 19). </p><p> Everyone probably has, more or less consciously formulated, an ideal standard of living, a level toward which he moves as income
14、 and other opportunities permit; he has also . . . a standard that he insists upon maintaining. To attain the first would be a highly desirable state of economic well-being, to attain the second is essential, and to fall
15、 below it is intolerable (Kyrk 1953, 374). </p><p> Each of these statements posits how specific changes in resources and/or preferences affect well-being. Yet all have been ignored in the recent expansion
16、of research on the consumer life cycle. Attempts to understand variation in family and consumer well-being over the life cycle have emphasized the specification of variables to capture the relevant demographic characteri
17、stics of each stage in the life cycle (Murphy and Staples 1979; Stampfl 1978). A growing literature on subjective assessments </p><p> Although variation in consumption needs and resources to meet them has
18、been considered extensively, no systematic empirical effort has been made to relate subjective well-being assessments to economic theories about life cycle consumption behavior. This conclusion is supported by the fact t
19、hat the literature on life satisfaction has relied on a single, short term measure of economic resources, current income, in conjunction with demographic variables to capture other influences of stage in the l</p>
20、<p> The research presented here is part of a larger project devoted to improving the specification and investigation of relationships among a more comprehensive array of objective economic variables and subjectiv
21、e well-being indicators than heretofore. Prior work on subjective well-being has taken as implicit that current income translates directly into resources for consumption. There has been very little recognition of theorie
22、s acknowledging the divergence between consumption and income that resul</p><p> While a positive relationship between current income and psychological well-being has been documented extensively, there is a
23、lso evidence of important exceptions. Campbell (1976) reviewed five national surveys, which all revealed that the proportion of "very happy" people increases with income level. However, a large minority of the
24、affluent describe themselves as less than very happy and a substantial minority of the least affluent claim they are very happy. Thus accurately evaluating the econo</p><p> The next section relies on the i
25、nsights of Modigliani, Duesenberry, and Kyrk to develop objective economic measures for life cycle income, relative income, and of deficits in resources to meet individual consumption aspirations, respectively. After exp
26、laining the nature of the data set, separate regression models are specified consistent with each of the theoretical economic well-being hypotheses. Then the estimated regression results are used to assess the relative e
27、xplanatory power of each mea</p><p> THEORIES OF ECONOMIC WELL-BEING</p><p> According to Duesenberry's theory of consumer behavior, "interdependent preferences" mean that the co
28、nsumer's satisfaction depends on the level of own consumption, as perceived relative to others'. Specifically, "when an individual makes an unfavorable comparison of his living standard . . . the individual
29、is dissatisfied with his position" (1949,32). Furthermore, the interdependence is connected to the motivation for saving because the dissatisfaction "arises from the rejection of impulses to s</p><p&
30、gt; One interpretation of the RIH that relates present to future consumption is as follows. Those consumers who are unable to "keep up with the Jones's" experience dissatisfaction as pressures mount to inc
31、rease current consumption above the level which is consistent with their desired level of future consumption. Empirically, this hypothesis can be examined by relating current household expenditures to those of other hous
32、eholds during the same period, holding income constant. Thus, relying on curren</p><p> Modigliani's LIH framework concerns optimal savings behavior that depends on and determines differences between cu
33、rrent income and expected future income. In its simplest "stripped down" form, the LIH posits life cycle paths for consumption, saving, and wealth that depend on the length of the work life, retirement age, and
34、 expected age at death, as well as the age profile of earnings (Modigliani 1986). Because utility maximization requires consumption smoothing over time, the path of wealth hold</p><p> Adult-Equivalent Cons
35、umption Needs</p><p> In addition to measures of economic well-being and life cycle stage effects, it was necessary to control for family needs in testing the relationship between the life cycle income hypo
36、thesis and life satisfaction. In previous studies of well-being, often such measures were either omitted or a gross indicator like family size was used. For this study, household equivalence scales were constructed (HH E
37、QUIVALENCE) to control for such effects. </p><p> The particular household equivalence measure used in this analysis was developed by Buse and Salathe (1978) and modified by Tedford, Capps, and Havlicek (TC
38、H) (1986). The primary advantage of the Buse and Salathe equivalence scale calculation is that the scale is expressed as a continuous rather than discrete function of age. TCH's contribution involved respecification
39、of the scaling functions in a manner consistent with the human development literature by augmenting stages first identified by L</p><p> The household equivalence measure was not included as a control in ei
40、ther the RIH or RDH models. It was not included in the RIH model because its construction is based on a life cycle theory and thus is highly correlated with the life cycle stage indicator variables. Life cycle variables
41、in the RIH model capture both life cycle and need effects. In the resource deficit model, no control for family needs was required, as respondents implicitly make such assessments in expressing what level of inc</p>
42、;<p> All three models were estimated using a weighted least squares regression analysis. Results are presented in Table 3. All model specifications explained a significant amount of variance (about 12 to 15 perc
43、ent) in the dependent variable, overall life satisfaction. The explained variance of a simple model including only current income and family size was about seven percent (Douthitt, MacDonald, and Mullis 1991). </p>
44、<p><b> SUMMARY</b></p><p> Generally, all three models of economic well-being perform favorably in explaining consumer utility or psychological well-being. The relative income hypothesi
45、s model is the simplest and most powerful of the three. The theoretical specification of the relative income model addresses the question of whether keeping up with the Jones's really contributes to or detracts from
46、one's overall life satisfaction. Results indicate that deviation from average peer expenditure patterns is important, but that</p><p> Two additional important conclusions from this work can be drawn. F
47、irst, a careful specification of economic variables in models explaining family life satisfaction has important payoffs in terms of explained variance. However, which economic theory of utility maximization is used may n
48、ot be as critical. The more complexly specified life cycle income hypothesis model does not perform any better than the other models with variables that are much easier to derive (but for Duesenberry's hypothesis <
49、;/p><p> 譯 文:消費(fèi)理論和消費(fèi)者主觀幸福評(píng)估</p><p><b> 摘要</b></p><p> 本文探討心理健康和目標(biāo)的關(guān)系以及用經(jīng)濟(jì)福祉來(lái)作為衡量三個(gè)不同的消費(fèi)行為的經(jīng)濟(jì)理論。包括生命周期收入假說(shuō),相對(duì)收入假說(shuō),資源赤字假說(shuō)方法和研究。 </p><p><b> 引言</b&
50、gt;</p><p> 這項(xiàng)研究是研究心理健康和目標(biāo)之間的關(guān)系,經(jīng)濟(jì)福祉衡量三個(gè)不同的消費(fèi)行為的經(jīng)濟(jì)理論。理論研究的是生命周期的收入假設(shè),相對(duì)收入假設(shè),假設(shè)資源不足。從威斯康星基本數(shù)據(jù)的分析結(jié)果表明,經(jīng)濟(jì)變量必須認(rèn)真地鞏固和支持經(jīng)濟(jì)推定,收入正在積極和生活滿意有關(guān)。這也容易地說(shuō)明與相對(duì)收入假設(shè)模式最大的差異和優(yōu)勢(shì)。 </p><p> 這份文件審查主觀的評(píng)價(jià)的福祉和客觀的經(jīng)濟(jì)變量測(cè)試
51、之間的關(guān)系和比較三種不同消費(fèi)行為的經(jīng)濟(jì)理論:莫生命周期的收入假設(shè)(1986);杜森伯里的相對(duì)收入假設(shè)(1949);和一個(gè)資源赤字假設(shè)歸咎于基爾克(1953)??陀^經(jīng)濟(jì)措施代表這三個(gè)假設(shè)旨在分析孤立和比較獨(dú)立影響主觀幸福。 </p><p> 以下介紹的三種不同型號(hào)消費(fèi)觀念的主要內(nèi)容及關(guān)系的變化 :</p><p> 假設(shè)效用最大化(和完善市場(chǎng)),所有的影響消費(fèi)者的資源,不是消費(fèi)者的任何
52、年齡,而只是取決于他的生活資源,不是目前的利息收入(莫1986,299)。 </p><p> 從偏好理論或邊際效用理論的觀點(diǎn)看,人類的欲望是特定商品的欲望,但沒(méi)有這些欲望是如何產(chǎn)生或說(shuō)它們是如何改變的理論,然而,這是消費(fèi)問(wèn)題,優(yōu)惠是相互依存(杜森伯里1949,19)。</p><p> 每個(gè)人都有可能不自覺(jué)地制定一個(gè)理想的生活水平,這一水平,對(duì)于他提出的收入和其他機(jī)會(huì)具有可能性;他對(duì)
53、于這個(gè)標(biāo)準(zhǔn),堅(jiān)持維護(hù)。為了實(shí)現(xiàn)第二種經(jīng)濟(jì)福祉,實(shí)現(xiàn)第一個(gè)理想是必不可少的,并且低于第一個(gè)是不能容忍(基爾克1953,374)。 </p><p> 每一個(gè)發(fā)言斷定資源如何具體變化影響偏好福祉。然而,所有最近擴(kuò)大研究的消費(fèi)生命周期被忽視了。試圖了解不同的家庭和消費(fèi)者福利的生命周期強(qiáng)調(diào)規(guī)格的變量來(lái)捕捉有關(guān)人口的特點(diǎn),在每個(gè)階段的生命周期(墨菲和糧食作物1979;stampfl1978)。越來(lái)越多的主觀評(píng)價(jià)文學(xué)的福祉
54、是出于關(guān)心而來(lái),特別是滿意減少階段(坎貝爾、Converse,和羅杰斯1976)。強(qiáng)調(diào)生命周期階段也是分析影響不斷變化的經(jīng)濟(jì)和人口的經(jīng)濟(jì)福利的一個(gè)關(guān)鍵變量(levy1987)。 </p><p> 不同的消費(fèi)需求和資源,滿足他們沒(méi)有系統(tǒng)化經(jīng)驗(yàn)的不足,主觀幸福評(píng)估經(jīng)濟(jì)理論已被廣泛認(rèn)為對(duì)生命周期消費(fèi)行為作出了努力。這一結(jié)論支持的是在生活滿意,依靠單一、短期的經(jīng)濟(jì)資源,捕捉目前其他影響收入與人口變量的階段,在生命中(
55、例如,阿拉特1977;安德魯斯1980;多倫溫德1973;費(fèi)爾南德斯和庫(kù)利克1981;霍爾1976;奧肯1984)。這里提出的研究是一個(gè)較大的項(xiàng)目,改善專門(mén)的規(guī)格和調(diào)查之間的關(guān)系,客觀經(jīng)濟(jì)變量和主觀幸福指標(biāo)比以往任何時(shí)候更周全。以前的工作的主觀幸福所采取的暗示,當(dāng)前的收入直接翻譯為資源消費(fèi)。 有了很少承認(rèn)理論承認(rèn)分歧的消費(fèi)和收入,結(jié)果需要節(jié)省,從未來(lái)借入的收入能力或壓力,以滿足潛在或?qū)嶋H增加的消費(fèi)需求。 但是儲(chǔ)蓄和消費(fèi)功能的經(jīng)濟(jì)理論和經(jīng)
56、驗(yàn)研究一再表示,最大限度地利用消費(fèi)者所有的收入(莫和布倫伯格1954),目前的消費(fèi)和收入可能是一個(gè)貧窮指標(biāo)(弗里德曼1957)。其他部門(mén)的金融安全無(wú)疑有助于某種意義上的福祉。例如個(gè)人年收入30000元,很有可能與其他金融資源偏離方面。一些低或消極凈值(即資產(chǎn)減負(fù)債),而有較高凈值,一些應(yīng)急資產(chǎn)相對(duì)不足。另一方面,很多人現(xiàn)有收入對(duì)未來(lái)收入可能出</p><p> 雖然目前收入和心理健康存在積極的關(guān)系已經(jīng)被廣泛證明
57、,但也有例外??藏悹?1976)審查了五個(gè)國(guó)家調(diào)查顯示,大部分的人“非常高興”人民收入水平增加。 但是,少數(shù)人的描述自己的富裕不到十分高興和大量少數(shù)最不富裕聲稱他們非常高興。因此,準(zhǔn)確地評(píng)估經(jīng)濟(jì)資源的關(guān)系,心理健康似乎需要以適當(dāng)?shù)慕?jīng)濟(jì)理論的額外客觀經(jīng)濟(jì)措施,。 </p><p> 下一條依靠杜森伯里和基爾克發(fā)展客觀經(jīng)濟(jì)措施的生命周期收入,相對(duì)收入和資源的赤字的見(jiàn)解,來(lái)滿足個(gè)人消費(fèi)愿望。不同的回歸模式符合規(guī)定的每
58、一個(gè)理論性的經(jīng)濟(jì)福利假設(shè)。當(dāng)時(shí)估計(jì)回歸結(jié)果是用來(lái)衡量相對(duì)解釋能力的,每一項(xiàng)措施和獲得的有關(guān)結(jié)論對(duì)受訪者主觀的整體福利在生命周期的影響為目前的研究提供解釋。 </p><p><b> 經(jīng)濟(jì)福祉理論</b></p><p> 根據(jù)杜森伯里的消費(fèi)行為理論“相互依存優(yōu)惠”意味著消費(fèi)者認(rèn)為相對(duì)其他人,滿意程度取決于自己的消費(fèi),具體來(lái)說(shuō)“當(dāng)個(gè)人比較不利時(shí),他的個(gè)人的立場(chǎng)不滿
59、意他的生活標(biāo)準(zhǔn)”(1949,32)。此外,連帶著相互依存的儲(chǔ)蓄動(dòng)機(jī)的不滿,因?yàn)椤皝?lái)自拒絕沖動(dòng)消費(fèi)”(1949,32)。因此,那些能夠消耗在以上的水平應(yīng)同行更滿意比那些不能,但他們也能夠節(jié)省足以滿足這一立場(chǎng)。關(guān)于這一重要警告儲(chǔ)蓄說(shuō)明消費(fèi)相對(duì)比較是與當(dāng)前和未來(lái)的收入水平。此外,它明確了相對(duì)收入假設(shè)(赫)和莫的生命周期理論的儲(chǔ)蓄(力)密切有關(guān),滿意取決于目前和預(yù)期收入。</p><p> 一種解釋是赫本未來(lái)消費(fèi),這些
60、消費(fèi)者無(wú)法跟上瓊斯的經(jīng)驗(yàn)不足,形成一種壓力加在目前的消費(fèi)水平之上,這是符合其預(yù)期未來(lái)消費(fèi)水平。根據(jù)經(jīng)驗(yàn),這一假設(shè)可由現(xiàn)有家庭支出有關(guān)的其他家庭在同一時(shí)期的收入。因此,依靠現(xiàn)有的數(shù)據(jù)來(lái)看,可以測(cè)試的假設(shè)是目前的資源是對(duì)未來(lái)滿意的決定因素。雖然這種測(cè)試需要完整的支出數(shù)據(jù),它可避免眾所周知的儲(chǔ)蓄獲得可靠數(shù)據(jù)的困難問(wèn)題。 </p><p> 莫利最佳儲(chǔ)蓄行為,取決于當(dāng)前的收入差異和預(yù)期未來(lái)收入。在簡(jiǎn)單的一個(gè)“剝削”的形
61、式下斷定的生命周期路徑消費(fèi)、儲(chǔ)蓄、財(cái)富,取決于工作生活的長(zhǎng)度,退休的年齡,預(yù)期死亡年齡,以及年齡收入(莫1986)。因?yàn)樽畲笙薅壤孟M(fèi)環(huán)節(jié)需要的路徑,財(cái)富具有丘形。在生命周期收入階段,家庭節(jié)省以積累財(cái)富,用以退休生活。因此,目前的消費(fèi)取決于各年齡層的整個(gè)收入。即使沒(méi)有過(guò)渡收入差異,目前收入水平可能大不相同,預(yù)計(jì)在隨后的時(shí)間是因?yàn)橐粋€(gè)特別的年齡收入。因此,研究莫的規(guī)格,公式包括目前和預(yù)期收入變量。此外,凈值(annuitized)進(jìn)入模
62、式,作為一個(gè)單獨(dú)變量預(yù)測(cè)到影響集團(tuán)現(xiàn)有的財(cái)富?;鶢柨?1953)建議的差距成為一個(gè)不甚滿意的資源愿望水平和實(shí)際經(jīng)驗(yàn)。她認(rèn)為,個(gè)人期望他們理想的生活標(biāo)準(zhǔn),根據(jù)個(gè)人的經(jīng)驗(yàn)和目標(biāo)方向,是當(dāng)前的收入和預(yù)期收入水平(1953)。雖然收入目標(biāo)可能包括觀察同事的消費(fèi)(杜森伯里也承認(rèn)生活水平是一個(gè)美國(guó)目標(biāo))基爾克的想法是消費(fèi)者最終確定并尋求解決自己的收入標(biāo)準(zhǔn),而不是其他人的標(biāo)準(zhǔn)。因此,基爾克的假設(shè)是獨(dú)特的。 </p><p>&
63、lt;b> 成人消費(fèi)需求</b></p><p> 此外,經(jīng)濟(jì)福利和生命周期階段影響措施,在測(cè)試之間有必要對(duì)家庭需要控制生命周期收入假說(shuō)和生活滿意度的關(guān)系。在之前的幸福研究,這些措施往往要么省略或類似家庭規(guī)模的總指標(biāo)。這項(xiàng)研究,控制家庭建造同等規(guī)模(HH等同)這種影響。 </p><p> 特別是家庭的措施等同于本分析是由布斯和salathe(1978)和經(jīng)tedf
64、ord,卡普斯和克(捷克斯洛伐克)(1986)。主要利用布斯和salathe同等規(guī)模計(jì)算,而不是獨(dú)有的職責(zé)。捷克斯洛伐克的貢獻(xiàn)respecification涉及的縮放功能,以符合人類發(fā)展文學(xué)擴(kuò)大確定的第一階段萊文森等人(1978)。像布斯和salathe、捷克斯洛伐克包含成人職能的立方花鍵功能的計(jì)算規(guī)模。在16筆變量是加權(quán)計(jì)算的家庭功能的年齡和性別特征和倒退的每月總支出的家庭獲得同等措施。</p><p> 家
65、庭等同措施不包括作為一個(gè)控制在赫或快速模式。這不包括在赫模式,是因?yàn)樗慕ㄔO(shè)是基于一個(gè)生命周期理論,是生命周期的指標(biāo)密切相關(guān)的階段變數(shù)。生命周期的變數(shù)捕捉生命周期的影響和需要。在資源不足模式,控制家庭需要是必須的,受訪者含蓄地作出評(píng)價(jià),表示什么樣的收入水平使他們感到可怕。 </p><p> 所有三種模式使用一個(gè)加權(quán)最小平方回歸分析,結(jié)果表明所有示范規(guī)格解釋了大量的差額(約12至15%)的變量,生活整體滿意。一
66、個(gè)簡(jiǎn)單的模式只包括當(dāng)前的收入和家庭規(guī)模約為0%(douthitt,麥克唐納,和穆利斯1991)。</p><p><b> 總結(jié)</b></p><p> 一般來(lái)說(shuō),經(jīng)濟(jì)福祉的三種模式中相對(duì)收入假說(shuō)模型是最簡(jiǎn)單,最強(qiáng)大的對(duì)消費(fèi)者的效用或心理福祉進(jìn)行解釋。該模型的理論規(guī)范的相對(duì)收入是否緊跟瓊斯,真正有助于從一個(gè)人的整體生活滿意度解釋問(wèn)題。結(jié)果表明,從重要的平均開(kāi)支模
67、式的偏差來(lái)看,支出低于平均水平,保持收入不變,生活滿意度提高了。雖然這似乎違反常理,僅側(cè)重洞察力。此外,因?yàn)閮?chǔ)蓄行為在許多時(shí)期發(fā)生了變化,主觀福祉不僅是目前的經(jīng)濟(jì)狀況,還考慮長(zhǎng)遠(yuǎn)的以及資源的功能為相對(duì)收入假說(shuō)的成功提供了有力的證據(jù)。 這項(xiàng)工作的兩個(gè)附加的可以得出的重要結(jié)論是:首先,家庭生活滿意度模型解釋經(jīng)濟(jì)變數(shù)以及回報(bào),然而,效用最大化的經(jīng)濟(jì)理論不能作為關(guān)鍵。在指定的生命周期的復(fù)雜化程度增加時(shí),收入假說(shuō)模型比變量更容易獲得(但D
溫馨提示
- 1. 本站所有資源如無(wú)特殊說(shuō)明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請(qǐng)下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
- 2. 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請(qǐng)聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權(quán)益歸上傳用戶所有。
- 3. 本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁(yè)內(nèi)容里面會(huì)有圖紙預(yù)覽,若沒(méi)有圖紙預(yù)覽就沒(méi)有圖紙。
- 4. 未經(jīng)權(quán)益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
- 5. 眾賞文庫(kù)僅提供信息存儲(chǔ)空間,僅對(duì)用戶上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護(hù)處理,對(duì)用戶上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對(duì)任何下載內(nèi)容負(fù)責(zé)。
- 6. 下載文件中如有侵權(quán)或不適當(dāng)內(nèi)容,請(qǐng)與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
- 7. 本站不保證下載資源的準(zhǔn)確性、安全性和完整性, 同時(shí)也不承擔(dān)用戶因使用這些下載資源對(duì)自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。
最新文檔
- [雙語(yǔ)翻譯]消費(fèi)者權(quán)利外文翻譯--約旦消費(fèi)者對(duì)消費(fèi)者權(quán)利的看法
- [雙語(yǔ)翻譯]消費(fèi)者權(quán)利外文翻譯--約旦消費(fèi)者對(duì)消費(fèi)者權(quán)利的看法(英文)
- [雙語(yǔ)翻譯]消費(fèi)者權(quán)利外文翻譯--約旦消費(fèi)者對(duì)消費(fèi)者權(quán)利的看法中英全
- 2015年消費(fèi)者權(quán)利外文翻譯--約旦消費(fèi)者對(duì)消費(fèi)者權(quán)利的看法
- 外文翻譯---臺(tái)灣消費(fèi)者與美國(guó)消費(fèi)者購(gòu)買(mǎi)心理研究
- 外文翻譯---臺(tái)灣消費(fèi)者與美國(guó)消費(fèi)者購(gòu)買(mǎi)心理研究
- 2015年消費(fèi)者權(quán)利外文翻譯--約旦消費(fèi)者對(duì)消費(fèi)者權(quán)利的看法.DOCX
- 外文翻譯---臺(tái)灣消費(fèi)者與美國(guó)消費(fèi)者購(gòu)買(mǎi)心理研究
- 中國(guó)消費(fèi)者貸款【外文翻譯】
- 2015年消費(fèi)者權(quán)利外文翻譯--約旦消費(fèi)者對(duì)消費(fèi)者權(quán)利的看法(英文).PDF
- 外文翻譯---臺(tái)灣消費(fèi)者與美國(guó)消費(fèi)者購(gòu)買(mǎi)心理研究(英文)
- 外文翻譯---臺(tái)灣消費(fèi)者與美國(guó)消費(fèi)者購(gòu)買(mǎi)心理研究.doc
- 外文翻譯---臺(tái)灣消費(fèi)者與美國(guó)消費(fèi)者購(gòu)買(mǎi)心理研究.doc
- 消費(fèi)者感知風(fēng)險(xiǎn)概念和模型【外文翻譯】
- 網(wǎng)上購(gòu)物消費(fèi)者動(dòng)機(jī)【外文翻譯】
- 外文翻譯---臺(tái)灣消費(fèi)者與美國(guó)消費(fèi)者購(gòu)買(mǎi)心理研究(英文).pdf
- 外文翻譯---臺(tái)灣消費(fèi)者與美國(guó)消費(fèi)者購(gòu)買(mǎi)心理研究(英文).pdf
- 外文翻譯--櫥窗展示和消費(fèi)者購(gòu)物決策(節(jié)選)
- 消費(fèi)者行為理論
- 綠色消費(fèi)者的買(mǎi)方特征和廣告策略【外文翻譯】
評(píng)論
0/150
提交評(píng)論